[House Hearing, 111 Congress] [From the U.S. Government Publishing Office] TOO BIG TO FAIL: THE ROLE FOR BANKRUPTCY AND ANTITRUST LAW IN FINANCIAL REGULATION REFORM (PART II) ======================================================================= HEARING BEFORE THE SUBCOMMITTEE ON COURTS AND COMPETITION POLICY OF THE COMMITTEE ON THE JUDICIARY HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES ONE HUNDRED ELEVENTH CONGRESS FIRST SESSION __________ NOVEMBER 17, 2009 __________ Serial No. 111-106 __________ Printed for the use of the Committee on the Judiciary [GRAPHIC NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT] Available via the World Wide Web: http://judiciary.house.gov _________ U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE 53-639 PDF WASHINGTON : 2010 ___________________________________________________________________________ For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Office, http://bookstore.gpo.gov. For more information, contact the GPO Customer Contact Center, U.S. Government Printing Office. Phone 202-512-1800, or 866-512-1800 (toll-free). E-mail, gpo@custhelp.com. COMMITTEE ON THE JUDICIARY JOHN CONYERS, Jr., Michigan, Chairman HOWARD L. BERMAN, California LAMAR SMITH, Texas RICK BOUCHER, Virginia F. JAMES SENSENBRENNER, Jr., JERROLD NADLER, New York Wisconsin ROBERT C. ``BOBBY'' SCOTT, Virginia HOWARD COBLE, North Carolina MELVIN L. WATT, North Carolina ELTON GALLEGLY, California ZOE LOFGREN, California BOB GOODLATTE, Virginia SHEILA JACKSON LEE, Texas DANIEL E. LUNGREN, California MAXINE WATERS, California DARRELL E. ISSA, California WILLIAM D. DELAHUNT, Massachusetts J. RANDY FORBES, Virginia ROBERT WEXLER, Florida STEVE KING, Iowa STEVE COHEN, Tennessee TRENT FRANKS, Arizona HENRY C. ``HANK'' JOHNSON, Jr., LOUIE GOHMERT, Texas Georgia JIM JORDAN, Ohio PEDRO PIERLUISI, Puerto Rico TED POE, Texas MIKE QUIGLEY, Illinois JASON CHAFFETZ, Utah JUDY CHU, California TOM ROONEY, Florida LUIS V. GUTIERREZ, Illinois GREGG HARPER, Mississippi TAMMY BALDWIN, Wisconsin CHARLES A. GONZALEZ, Texas ANTHONY D. WEINER, New York ADAM B. SCHIFF, California LINDA T. SANCHEZ, California DEBBIE WASSERMAN SCHULTZ, Florida DANIEL MAFFEI, New York Perry Apelbaum, Majority Staff Director and Chief Counsel Sean McLaughlin, Minority Chief of Staff and General Counsel ------ Subcommittee on Courts and Competition Policy HENRY C. ``HANK'' JOHNSON, Jr., Georgia, Chairman JOHN CONYERS, Jr., Michigan HOWARD COBLE, North Carolina RICK BOUCHER, Virginia JASON CHAFFETZ, Utah ROBERT WEXLER, Florida BOB GOODLATTE, Virginia CHARLES A. GONZALEZ, Texas F. JAMES SENSENBRENNER, Jr., SHEILA JACKSON LEE, Texas Wisconsin MELVIN L. WATT, North Carolina DARRELL ISSA, California MIKE QUIGLEY, Illinois GREGG HARPER, Mississippi DANIEL MAFFEI, New York Christal Sheppard, Chief Counsel Blaine Merritt, Minority Counsel C O N T E N T S ---------- NOVEMBER 17, 2009 Page OPENING STATEMENTS The Honorable Henry C. ``Hank'' Johnson, Jr., a Representative in Congress from the State of Georgia, and Chairman, Subcommittee on Courts and Competition Policy............................... 1 The Honorable Howard Coble, a Representative in Congress from the State of North Carolina, and Ranking Member, Subcommittee on Courts and Competition Policy.................................. 2 The Honorable John Conyers, Jr., a Representative in Congress from the State of Michigan, Chairman, Committee on the Judiciary, and Ranking Member, Subcommittee on Courts and Competition Policy............................................. 3 The Honorable Jason Chaffetz, a Representative in Congress from the State of Utah, and Member, Subcommittee on Courts and Competition Policy............................................. 6 WITNESSES Mr. Christopher L. Sagers, Associate Professor of Law, Cleveland- Marshall College of Law, Cleveland, OH Oral Testimony................................................. 8 Prepared Statement............................................. 10 Mr. Edwin E. Smith, Bingham McCutchen, LLP, on behalf of the National Bankruptcy Conference, Fairfax, VA Oral Testimony................................................. 47 Prepared Statement............................................. 49 Mr. Michael A. Rosenthal, Gibson, Dunn & Crutcher, LLP, New York, NY Oral Testimony................................................. 58 Prepared Statement............................................. 60 Mr. Charles W. Calomiris, Henry Kaufman Professor of Financial Institutions, Columbia Business School, New York, NY Oral Testimony................................................. 105 Prepared Statement............................................. 108 LETTERS, STATEMENTS, ETC., SUBMITTED FOR THE HEARING Prepared Statement of the Honorable John Conyers, Jr., a Representative in Congress from the State of Michigan, Chairman, Committee on the Judiciary, and Member, Subcommittee on Courts and Competition Policy............................... 4 Prepared Statement of the Honorable Steve Cohen, a Representative in Congress from the State of Tennessee, and Chairman, Subcommittee on Commercial and Administrative Law.............. 7 Prepared Statement of the Honorable Lamar Smith, a Representative in Congress from the State of Texas, and Ranking Member, Committee on the Judiciary..................................... 123 TOO BIG TO FAIL: THE ROLE FOR BANKRUPTCY AND ANTITRUST LAW IN FINANCIAL REGULATION REFORM (PART II) ---------- TUESDAY, NOVEMBER 17, 2009 House of Representatives, Subcommittee on Courts and Competition Policy Committee on the Judiciary, Washington, DC. The Subcommittee met, pursuant to notice, at 1:02 p.m., in room 2237, Rayburn House Office Building, the Honorable Henry C. ``Hank'' Johnson, Jr. (Chairman of the Subcommittee) presiding. Present: Representatives Johnson, Conyers, Coble, Chaffetz, and Goodlatte. Staff present: (Majority) Christal Sheppard, Subcommittee Chief Counsel; Anant Raut, Counsel; Elisabeth Stein, Counsel; Rosalind Jackson, Professional Staff Member; and (Minority) Stewart Jeffries, Counsel. Mr. Johnson. This hearing on the Committee on the Judiciary, Subcommittee on Courts and Competition Policy will now come to order. Without objection, the Chair is authorized to declare a recess. Today the Subcommittee holds its second hearing examining the implications of companies that are ``Too big to Fail.'' During our first hearing in April, we asked two questions: Are there such things as institutions that are too big to fail? And if so, do they represent a failure of the antitrust laws? At the time, our panel of experts concluded that yes, there are companies whose size makes them systematically significant in our economy. However, the antitrust laws don't need to be changed on account of these companies. If anything, these companies merit greater enforcement of the antitrust laws that currently exist. Our country remains in the grip of a grim economic downturn. Since the collapse of Lehman Brothers in September of 2008, the unemployment rate in my home State of Georgia has climbed from 6.6 percent to 10.2 percent today. The metropolitan Atlanta area has lost more than 124,000 jobs during that time. Today we have before us several pieces of legislation proposed by the Treasury to systematically unwind these large companies once they are on the verge of failure. The Administration points to the collapse of companies like Lehman Brothers and warns that this new authority is vital to preventing another big company from bringing down the economy as it goes under. I, for one, am skeptical. The legislation proposed by the Treasury raises a number of troubling issues under this Subcommittee's jurisdiction. The resolution authority would, in some instances, sidestep antitrust oversight entirely. Decisions about which competitor gets a failing company's assets could be made without the input of the antitrust enforcement agencies, creating a new generation of too big to fail companies requiring another multibillion-dollar bailout down the road. Courts which have traditionally played a pivotal role in the normal bankruptcy process would also have their oversight diminished. Decisions about the distribution of assets could be made without a judge watching over the process to make sure that the shareholders and the general public are treated fairly. In the wake of great crises, whether financial or national security in nature, it is tempting for new Administrations to dismiss existing law as inadequate and claim that new approaches and new powers are necessary for a new kind of threat. But what we have learned is that agencies empowered with emergency authority can't be solely responsible for determining when and how it gets used. Checks and balances are a necessary restraint on the powers granted by Congress. I hope that our discussion today will help us better understand what protections need to be built into this proposed resolution authority to ensure that it is used sparingly and in the best interests of the American public. I now recognize my colleague Howard Coble, the distinguished Ranking Member of the Subcommittee, for his opening remarks. Mr. Coble. I thank you, Mr. Chairman. And good to have the panelists with us today. Mr. Chairman, thank you for calling today's hearing, which is the second that this Subcommittee has held on the role of antitrust in correcting the current economic crisis. Last April, you will recall we heard from former acting assistant attorney general Deb Garza that antitrust laws did not create the current economic crisis, and the antitrust division was capable of conducting antitrust review of proposed asset sales under the TARP plan. That is the Troubled Asset Relief Program. Last month I attended a Commercial and Administrative Law Subcommittee hearing on the role of the bankruptcy law and antitrust in resolving the existing financial crisis. At that hearing, under direct questioning from Chairman Conyers, representatives of the Treasury Department and the Federal Deposit Insurance Commission told the Subcommittee that the Administration's bill did not alter antitrust review of any proposed sale of assets in a government takeover of a failing financial entity. However, it appears from a subsequent markup by the Financial Services Committee and through written statements of at least some of the witnesses here today that this proposal does alter antitrust review. So my question to all the witnesses is does this bill alter antitrust review and, if so, how is it altered, and does it protect consumers? The proposed resolution authority that is before this Congress does not change my mind about the wisdom or lack thereof of governmental bailouts. The Constitution gives Congress the authority to establish bankruptcy laws and procedures, and in my estimation the bankruptcy system has many more public checks and balances. It is my understanding, Mr. Chairman that many of our colleagues on the Financial Services Committee and on the Judiciary Committee have suggested some changes to the bankruptcy laws to address this kind of large-scale financial crisis that we faced last year. Personally, I am far more comfortable with that approach to this issue, because it is non-biased. It is proven and reliable. And it provides a solid foundation from which businesses can recover. In any event, I would like to thank you, Mr. Chairman, and Chairman Johnson for protecting the Committee's jurisdiction with respect to bankruptcy and antitrust laws. These well-established laws have been the bulwark of America's capitalist system and any financial services reform should stem from their well-accepted principles. And, Mr. Chairman, I am going to have to depart imminently because I am scheduled to handle two bills on the floor, but the distinguished gentleman from Utah has promised to stand in for me, if that is okay. And I yield back. Mr. Johnson. I thank the gentleman for his statement. And I now recognize John Conyers, a distinguished Member of the Subcommittee and also the Chairman of the Committee on Judiciary. Mr. Conyers. Thank you very much, Chairman Johnson. And to my colleagues here, this is a hearing that is part of the larger financial regulatory reform package that we have jurisdiction over. That is, as I have explained, Title 7, improvements to regulation of over-the-counter derivatives, and Title 12, enhanced resolution authority. And I am grateful for the four witnesses that are here. Now, to me, our jurisdiction has been delineated. The Chairman of Finance Committee, Chairman Frank, has assured us that our determinations in these two titles will be adhered to. At the same time, we have the larger issue, and I don't know how we go about taking both of these things into consideration. I think it is a mistake for us to think only narrowly in terms of our two titles in the bill, because ultimately we will all be collectively voting on the larger bill. And we have had hearings. I have two folders of hearings of the Committee. Some have been in your Committee. I think one has been in Chairman Cohen's Committee. And we have circling overhead--and I would encourage the witnesses to feel free to go beyond the titles that we have actual jurisdiction. But I have got a notebook that tries to lay out the larger positions on this financial regulatory reform, which is coming now after more than a trillion dollars has already been expended. I mean, somebody needs to help me understand how we just thought about regulatory reform and the horse is out of the barn. Now, Chris Dodd and Barney Frank have two seriously different views about this thing. And Charles Schumer has yet another position on this. And the gentleman, I think, from Alabama, Shelby, has a position on this. The Nobel economist Joseph Stiglitz has a very distinct view about this. And so to me, Chairman Johnson and my colleagues, what becomes important here is that we try to understand the relationship between what is in our jurisdiction and what everybody else is thinking and doing both in the other body and in the House--the Finance Committee, the Committees on the--in the Senate. And of course, the Administration has its team that is sort of omnipresent in this whole situation. So I am going to submit an opening statement and look forward to the testimony from our witnesses. Thank you. [The prepared statement of Mr. Conyers follows:] Prepared Statement of the Honorable John Conyers, Jr., a Representative in Congress from the State of Michigan, Chairman, Committee on the Judiciary, and Member, Subcommittee on Courts and Competition Policy The financial regulatory reform package incubated in the Treasury Department and hatched in the Financial Services Committee appears to be in ailing health. The effort to regulate financial derivatives, the complex and highly speculative instruments at the heart of the meltdown last year, and the effort to create a new Consumer Financial Protection Agency to protect Americans from abusive, deceptive, and predatory lending, are both being targeted by lobbyists intent on weakening them. If the lobbyists succeed--and right now they appear to be gaining-- this important effort will be squandered, and the resulting legislation won't be worth supporting. Turning to the proposed new special resolution authority for the FDIC to take over failing financial institutions that are so interconnected to the wider financial system that their failure puts the wider system at undue risk, there is another danger--that if we are not careful, we will end up throwing some fundamental American values overboard. We need to make sure that doesn't happen. We must ensure that the rights of innocent citizens who get caught up in the tangents of a giant financial institution's far-flung activities are not cast aside, while favored interests are allowed to jump to the head of the line and grab the lion's share. We must preserve full-strength antitrust authority against anticompetitive mergers, so we don't wake up with just a handful of financial institutions that are even more gargantuan than the ones we started with. To ensure these values are protected, we can't just turn everything over to a government liquidator and stand back. We need to preserve the role of bankruptcy law in providing fair treatment for all who have claims against the financial institution, not just the favored few. And we need to preserve the role of the antitrust laws, in all of their vitality. If extraordinary powers are needed to respond to a systemic financial emergency, we should make sure that those powers are triggered only when there truly is such an emergency. We should make sure that those powers are limited in scope and duration--that they displace the important American values reflected in the bankruptcy and antitrust laws, if at all, only to the limited extent, and only for the limited duration, that is necessary for responding effectively to the emergency. And we should make sure that any harm to those values that results from the exercise of those powers should be reversible once the emergency has subsided. We need to keep in mind that this is not about bailing out Wall Street. It is not about helping the institutions that brought us this crisis pay their brokers billions of dollars in new bonuses. It is not about funneling money to those institutions as counterparties in derivative contracts, as a just-released report by the TARP Inspector General indicates Secretary Geithner was instrumental in doing last year when he was head of the Federal Reserve Bank in New York. It is not about excusing those institutions from giving struggling homeowners a chance at reasonable mortgage terms that avoid needless foreclosures. I for one am not comforted by Goldman Sachs Chairman and CEO Lloyd Blankfein's recent statement insisting that he is just a banker ``doing God's work'' and that his mammoth company is fulfilling ``a social purpose.'' Resurgent Wall Street profits and bonuses clearly are not trickling down to Main Street, or Woodward Avenue. In Detroit, the unemployment rate is nearly 28 percent. 195 homes there are being taken into the foreclosure process each day. One in three people in my district are at or below the poverty line. Let's not forget the lessons of the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act of 1999 and the Glass-Steagall Act of 1933. Ten years ago, Gramm-Leach-Bliley repealed the firewall set up in Glass-Steagle between the casino on Wall Street and the private investment engines of Main Street. The repeal allowed for the creation of giant financial supermarkets that could own investment banks, commercial banks, and insurance firms, thereby clearing the way for consolidation into companies too big and intertwined to fail. It also led to deregulation that helped cause the current economic crisis. I support the efforts in the Financial Services Committee to build the regulatory infrastructure needed to protect our economy against ever again being held hostage to fears that irresponsible financial giants are too big to fail. Our job in the Judiciary Committee is to ensure that this is accomplished in an effective and responsible manner that respects these other important American values. So I am pleased that the Courts and Competition Subcommittee is continuing our examination into these issues. I hope our witnesses today can shed light on three issues in the legislation to establish special resolution authority for financial institutions that pose undue systemic risk. First, are there adequate antitrust safeguards? We don't want our response to a financial crisis to lead to even larger and more concentrated institutions, with less competition, and higher prices for consumers. FDIC Special Advisor for Policy Michael Krimminger's statement before our Committee last month that ``in a systemic context, there can be cases in which there is an override of the anti-competitive consequences'' was troubling to those who care about our economic freedoms. Those considerations need to be carefully reconciled, not set against each other. I hope our witnesses can address how to maintain meaningful antitrust values under the new resolution mechanism. Second, are there fair and balanced protections for those affected by the insolvency? The standard should be the protections set out carefully in our Bankruptcy Code. Any departures from those Bankruptcy Code protections should be few, and justified, and each carefully limited in scope and duration to what is necessary to avert the systemic financial crisis. The Financial Services Committee bill is modeled on the authority given to the FDIC when a bank with FDIC-insured deposits fails. But the powers and priorities that are appropriate when FDIC- insured deposits are a dominant factor may not be appropriate when there is a greater variety of competing claims and claimants--labor contracts, pensions, and garden variety business debts, to name just a few. So while a receiver should have the power to act quickly to conserve systemically critical assets and liabilities, that power should be exercised in a manner that respects the rights of other innocent parties. I hope our witnesses today can address how to fairly protect these rights in the context of the need for quick action in a financial emergency, and create a measure of predictability that will enhance stability. Third, is there appropriate judicial review to guard against arbitrary and unfair government action? Under the Bankruptcy Code, it is a court that appoints a trustee to act as conservator or liquidator, oversees the trustee, and ultimately reviews and approves the process by which the business is reorganized or liquidated and claims are resolved. Under the Financial Services Committee bill, once the failure of the business is deemed to be a systemic risk to the financial system, the new conservator or receiver takes over. Any bankruptcy proceedings are abruptly terminated, and new bankruptcy proceedings are precluded. Instead of an open process, under uniform rules, with direct court oversight, we have an opaque process, under procedures that give the conservator or receiver broad discretion. I hope our witnesses can address how to make the resolution process more transparent and predictable, under appropriate judicial review. Clearly, the status quo, where too-big-to-fail institutions have privatized gains and received taxpayer-subsidized losses, is not acceptable. We need a workable mechanism to allow large, complex, interconnected, global financial companies to fail when they should, while managing the ripple effects. But we need to ensure that due process, fairness, transparency, and pro-competition principles are core ingredients of that mechanism. I commend the collaboration between Courts and Competition Policy Subcommittee Chairman Hank Johnson and Commercial and Administrative Law Subcommittee Chairman Steve Cohen in putting together this third in a series of important and thought-provoking hearings on the too-big-to- fail issue, and I look forward to the testimony. __________ Mr. Johnson. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I now recognize the gentleman from Utah, Mr. Chaffetz, for his statement. Mr. Chaffetz. Well, thank you. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And thank you, Chairman Conyers and Ranking Member Coble. And I appreciate the witnesses being here today. This is a very, very important subject and topic. I want to do more hearing than making a statement. I just wish to wholeheartedly support the verbal comments Chairman Conyers made and some of the deep concerns about the various approaches to this. I, too, have some concerns I would appreciate being addressed and I am sure you share many of these as well. I want to make sure we are staying within the constitutional duties and bounds that we are--have been given in our Constitution. I worry about our troubled firms getting even bigger. You know, one of the amazing statistics through all this is we talk about too big to fail--is if you actually go back and analyze these firms, we have less firms and they are even bigger than ever, and so have--through our public policy actually made the situation more vulnerable as opposed to actually solving it. Obviously, we want to ensure the American people that we are doing--be good stewards of their money. I have serious troubles and concerns with the TARP, and the bailouts, and the so-called stimulus, and things that have gone on in the past. I want to make sure that we are maximizing transparency. I think one of the benefits that--through going through bankruptcy, as painful and as derogatory as that term might be, there are certainly benefits in terms of exposure in going through a process. We have seen companies, large companies, very successfully go through the bankruptcy process and then go on to thrive. And I want to make sure that we don't--aren't injecting politics into it. I think to the degree we can have an even hand and that public policy is not driven by political maneuvering, the better the system will be. So again, thank you, Chairman, for calling this hearing. I look forward to the interaction and appreciate you all being here today. Thank you. Yield back. Mr. Johnson. I thank the gentleman for his opening statement. All Members' opening statements will be included in the record. And I would like to enter into the record a statement from our esteemed colleague, the Chairman of the Commercial and Administrative Law Subcommittee, Mr. Steve Cohen of Tennessee. [The prepared statement of Mr. Cohen follows:] Prepared Statement of the Honorable Steve Cohen, a Representative in Congress from the State of Tennessee, and Chairman, Subcommittee on Commercial and Administrative Law I applaud Chairman Hank Johnson and the Subcommittee on Courts and Competition Policy for continuing the House Judiciary Committee's inquiry into the Administration's proposal for enhanced resolution authority to wind-down failing, systemically important non-bank financial institutions. Several weeks ago, I presided over Part I of this hearing series before the Subcommittee on Commercial and Administrative Law. During that hearing, my Subcommittee posed some tough questions to Administration officials concerning the need for resolution authority for such nonbank institutions as well as the numerous bankruptcy, administrative law, and antitrust concerns raised by the Administration's proposal. We also heard from several bankruptcy and antitrust experts who further elaborated on these concerns. The Administration's resolution authority proposal would create an alternative to the bankruptcy system for dealing with failing non-bank financial institutions that are so interconnected with the Nation's financial system that their disorderly failure would destabilize the national and global financial systems. The ordinary bankruptcy process, it is said, would be too slow to deal with the imminent collapse of such institutions and would create too much uncertainty in the financial markets. The proposed resolution authority would be modeled on the authority of the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation to wind- down failing commercial banks. While I understand the Administration's desire for the authority to act quickly to stave off dangerous shocks to the Nation's financial system, I am concerned that its proposed resolution process lacks the transparency and due process safeguards of the bankruptcy process. I am not unsympathetic to the argument that some type of authority for the executive branch to act quickly in the face of the impending failure of a systemically important nonbank financial institution is important. What I am not yet convinced of is that an alternative to bankruptcy is needed with respect to the claims resolution process--that is, the process that occurs after a failing firm has been stabilized and its core assets have been sold to a third party or transferred to a bridge holding company. I am particularly concerned about the effect of the Administration's proposal with respect to claims for employee and retiree compensation and benefits. I am also deeply concerned about the creation of the Financial Services Oversight Council, which, under the legislation, would not be an ``agency'' for purposes of any State or Federal law and, therefore, not subject to the Administrative Procedure Act and other restrictions on agency power. As I have said before in other contexts, as a legislator for more than 30 years, such vast expansions of unfettered executive power trouble me greatly. The formation of the Council should be reconsidered. Even if not eliminated, there should be far greater Congressional oversight authority over the Council's activities. __________ Mr. Johnson. With his oversight over the bankruptcy laws, Chairman Cohen shares our interest and concerns regarding the proposed reform legislation. And without objection, I will so include his statement. Now, I am now pleased to introduce the witnesses for today's hearing. Our first witness is Professor Chris Sagers. Professor Chris Sagers is an Associate Professor of Law at the Cleveland Marshall College of Law in Cleveland, Ohio. He is an expert in the fields of antitrust and corporate law. Welcome, Professor Sagers. Our next witness is Mr. Edwin Smith. Mr. Smith is a Partner at the law firm of Bingham McCutchen LLP. He is here today testifying on behalf of the National Bankruptcy Conference. Welcome, Mr. Smith. Next we have Mr. Michael A. Rosenthal, who is a partner at the law firm of Gibson Dunn & Crutcher LLP. Mr. Rosenthal is co-chair of the firm's business restructuring and reorganization practice group. Welcome, Mr. Rosenthal. And finally, we have Professor Charles Calomiris. Professor Calomiris is the Henry Kaufman Professor of Financial Institutions at Columbia Business School. Welcome, Professor Calomiris. Thank you all for your willingness to participate in today's hearing. Without objection, your written statements will be placed into the record, and we would ask that you limit your oral remarks to 5 minutes. You will note that we have a lighting system that starts with a green light. At 4 minutes, it turns yellow and then red at 5 minutes. After each witness has presented his or her testimony, Subcommittee Members will be permitted to ask questions subject to the 5-minute rule limit. Professor Sagers, please begin your testimony. STATEMENT CHRISTOPHER L. SAGERS, ASSOCIATE PROFESSOR OF LAW, CLEVELAND-MARSHALL COLLEGE OF LAW, CLEVELAND, OH Mr. Sagers. Thank you, Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee. It is, again, my pleasure and privilege to be here. I am glad that the larger question has been asked about what is an appropriate approach to this problem overall, rather than the specific antitrust questions that I was asked to talk about. I wish I was competent to give some plenary answer to that question and I am not. But I can answer one big question that is relevant to it. And I have to begin by disagreeing with something that Ms. Garza said. Her comment was quoted again here today. I am not sure this is a very widely held view or a very popular one, but Ms. Garza, again, was acting assistant attorney general for antitrust in the Justice Department. She was also chair of the Antitrust Modernization Commission a couple years ago. She is an eminent figure in antitrust and I am sure that many, many people share her view. I happen to think that she is wrong in that she said antitrust didn't cause this problem. I would be the last person to say that antitrust is the only explanation for this problem, but let me say one thing. We have thousands and thousands of Federal statutes and regulations, and we have precisely one that is designed to deal with the size and power of private entities, and that is Clayton Act Section 7. Clayton Act Section 7 nominally has applied to all the many mergers and acquisitions that gave rise to TBF--excuse me, TBTF firms. It has never been applied in a way that has taken into consideration systemic risk. Many people right now would say it is impossible for that to be done. It shouldn't be done. My basic point here today is that that being the case, we don't have any law anywhere to deal with this problem. Dealing with that problem is a much bigger question, I suppose, than I could really talk about in 5 minutes. It is not addressed in my written testimony, so I won't pursue it. But for what it is worth, that issue is not on the table right now anywhere. And I personally think it is a serious problem with the overall approach to financial regulatory reform. Having said all that, I only have a couple of minutes left to summarize the rest of my testimony. So let me say, rather than digging into the details of what is quite a complicated issue, I think that everything I had to say in what I--my written submission and anything I would have to say today in person basically addresses one big issue. And that is that there is an attitude that has become quite common, especially among the courts and, first among them, the Supreme Court that antitrust, however venerable and useful it might be in some circumstances, is generally a bit of a tedious problem. It is costly, it is clumsy and it is to be avoided whenever it can. With respect, I happen to believe that that is incorrect. And as a peripheral observer of this Committee's process during the last couple of months, I am very pleased to say my impression is that that sense is shared by at least some Members of the Committee, and my impression is, then, that that is shared by Members of both parties, at least from what I have been able to observe, and that makes me very happy. The problem is I happen to think that that attitude is reflected in this bill in many ways. It is not anywhere explicitly stated in any of the Administration's bills, but-- and it may not have been deliberate, but my impression generally is that throughout most of the Administration's financial regulatory reform package, the attitude has been ``we should avoid or limit antitrust wherever possible because it will get in the way of other regulatory objectives.'' My sense, again, is that that is unfortunate both because I think that the difficulty that is said to be associated with antitrust in these markets is overstated, and maybe more importantly, because competition issues, issues of concentration and collusion in financial markets, are actually pretty serious, and not only in the--with respect to the sort of systemic risk problems I began with. They are also serious in more traditional--the more traditional sense that those problems limit allocational efficiency in these markets in serious ways. [The prepared statement of Mr. Sagers follows:] Prepared Statement of Christopher L. Sagers [GRAPHICS NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT] __________ Mr. Johnson. Thank you, Professor Sagers. Mr. Smith, would you proceed, please? TESTIMONY OF EDWIN E. SMITH, BINGHAM McCUTCHEN, LLP, ON BEHALF OF THE NATIONAL BANKRUPTCY CONFERENCE, FAIRFAX, VA Mr. Smith. Thank you. Mr. Johnson. I think we have an elementary school student handling our audiovisual, so give us just a second. Mr. Smith. Can you hear me on this microphone? Why don't I proceed, then? Thank you. Can you hear me now? Okay. Thank you, Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee, and my name is Edwin Smith. I am here on behalf of the National Bankruptcy Conference. For those of you who don't know, the National Bankruptcy Conference is a nonprofit, nonpartisan self-supporting organization of about 60 lawyers, academicians and judges. We have historically advised Congress on bankruptcy issues, and so we are before you today to talk about the resolution authority issues that are under discussion in the current bill. Part of our concern as a member of the National Bankruptcy Conference relates to, of all things, avoiding bankruptcy. What we have noticed is that where you start devising back-end rules like you are talking about with the resolution authority, that tends to affect the availability and cost of credit. To the extent that rules are not transparent, to the extent that they are uncertain, to the extent that they are unfair, what that does is it tends to make lenders more reticent about extending credit or doing so, if they do so at all, at much higher prices. And we have seen many, many companies avoid bankruptcy because they were able to get credit. They were able to get credit at affordable rates. They were able to address short- term needs. They were able to reorganize. And one of the things that we really would hate to see in a resolution authority bill are rules that tend to discourage the availability of credit or to increase the price of credit because we are afraid that what that might do is to increase the systemic risk that you are all trying to avoid. Now, what is it about the resolution authority discussions today that raise these issues as transparency, certainty and fairness? One is if there is going to be a system where there are too-big-to-fail companies that get identified, that should be transparent. It should be apparent for extenders of credit to know in advance when they are thinking of extending credit whether someone is going to be on the list and, if so, whether they are going to be subject to this entire scheme. To the extent that they don't know that, then they are going to have to make their credit decisions based on that lack of transparency, and that is going to increase the cost of credit or probably decrease its availability. We also are looking at certainty. How can these rules create certainty? And one of the things that is of concern is what happens when the Federal agency comes in and it rescues an organization that is too big to fail. It might find a buyer. It might create some sort of a bridge entity. But it would take the core systemic risk assets, as we understand them, and put them somewhere else--in a buyer, in a bridge entity. And then there would need to be at that particular point some claims resolution process. There would have to be a way of dealing with the assets that are left behind and the unassumed liabilities. And those rules are going to have to be very certain. And we think that the bankruptcy rules are actually in much better shape right now to deal with the assets that are left behind than the proposed FDIC rules, which we don't think are as well known, or as developed or as detailed as what you see in bankruptcy. And then we think the process has to be a fair process. If creditors are concerned that the process is unfair, once again they are going to be reluctant to extend credit or to do so--if they do so, they would do so at a higher price. We think, once again, the bankruptcy rules for dealing with the assets and unassumed liabilities that are left behind are much fairer to deal with that, not only just because they are more well known and well developed and more detailed, but also there are open proceedings. People get judicial review. The standards for review are much tighter than would be in the case of an administrative proceeding. And then as a matter of fairness, we have a rule in the bankruptcy code that says where you have a Chapter 11 plan and one creditor would be worse off under the plan than it would be on liquidation, that plan cannot be confirmed. And that was done out of fairness, with constitutional implications. There should be a similar rule here. If a creditor would get less under these rules that you are devising now--the creditor should be no worse off than it would be if the entity were liquidated, as a matter of fairness. Thank you, gentlemen. [The prepared statement of Mr. Smith follows:] Prepared Statement of Edwin E. Smith [GRAPHICS NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT] __________ Mr. Johnson. Thank you, Mr. Smith. Now we will hear from Mr. Rosenthal. TESTIMONY OF MICHAEL A. ROSENTHAL, GIBSON, DUNN & CRUTCHER, LLP, NEW YORK, NY Mr. Rosenthal. I will try to use--let me try to use this microphone. It seems to be better. Chairman Johnson, other Members of the Subcommittee, thank you for inviting me to testify today. I have spent 30 years in my legal career focusing on representation of financially distressed debtors and their creditors in a wide variety of industries. I believe that in addition to crafting a resolution regime that assures that there is no institution that is too big to fail, there should be two overarching goals of the legislation. The first relates to flexibility. We need to give the government the ability to act quickly to construct solutions to problems with these companies. The second, though, relates to predictability. Market stability requires predictable results. And if creditors are unable to rely on the predictability of expected returns, they may either restrict credit extensions, as Mr. Smith said, or extract excessively high risk premiums. While reform is clearly complicated, I firmly believe the foundation for reform should be the simple principle that absent compelling public policy reasons to the contrary, we should base a new system as much as possible on what market participants know, understand and have relied on. The new system must accomplish the goal of managing or restoring market stability, but do so in a way that does as little violence as possible to creditor expectations. Congress essentially has two existing regimes to choose from, the FDIA, which is used to resolve bank failures, and the bankruptcy code, which is used to resolve virtually all other business failures. The proposed legislation draws primarily from the FDIA but, in my view, could benefit significantly from the adoption of more features of the bankruptcy code. In part, this is because the bankruptcy code's concepts, including those that govern the judicial review of creditor claims, work better in the face of a system-shaking failure of a non-bank entity. And in part, this is because creditors of these companies understand and have structured and priced their transactions on their expectations about the application and the predictability of the bankruptcy code. The revisions to the legislation that I have proposed, taken together, create a hybrid between the FDIA and the bankruptcy code. They marry the bankruptcy code's basic creditor protections, including judicial review, transparency, predictability, with the FDIA's flexibility to address quickly the systemic repercussions of the failure of a significant financial entity. There are two distinct phases of a covered financial company's collapse which must be addressed by the legislation. The first is the initial phase, which is the crisis, where the FDIC must be given flexibility and discretion to act quickly and decisively to avert the crisis. We have proposed that during this 30-or-so-day-period, short period, the FDIC could act without contemporaneous oversight by a court. But after the financial crisis has been averted, a second phase of the process begins. During this second phase, the FDIC must administer the underlying liquidation of the failed entity, including resolution of any disputes with creditors. We have proposed that the FDIC's actions during this second phase would be subject to the oversight of the bankruptcy court. The bankruptcy court would apply the same procedures, precedents and adjudicative process that it employs every single day and that market participants already know, understand, rely on and expect. Time doesn't permit a discussion of the other specific changes that I have recommended, but they are summarized in my testimony and its--and its attachments. These changes include incorporation of the bankruptcy code's concepts regarding claim determinations, preference in fraudulent conveyances, contract rejections, reporting, valuation and treatment of secured claims. While you might ultimately enact a resolution system that is more administrative in nature than I have outlined, I encourage you even then to implement as many of the recommendations as possible to minimize the disruption to creditors' expectations. I commend the Committee for taking the time to consider this important topic and, again, appreciate the opportunity to speak with you today. [The prepared statement of Mr. Rosenthal follows:] Prepared Statement of Michael A. Rosenthal [GRAPHICS NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT] ATTACHMENT 1 [GRAPHICS NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT] ATTACHMENT 2 [GRAPHICS NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT] __________ Mr. Johnson. Thank you, Mr. Rosenthal. And last, but not least, Professor Calomiris? TESTIMONY OF CHARLES W. CALOMIRIS, HENRY KAUFMAN PROFESSOR OF FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS, COLUMBIA BUSINESS SCHOOL, NEW YORK, NY Mr. Calomiris. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, distinguished Members. It is a pleasure to appear here today. I am going to address briefly in my oral comments two issues--the best way to reform laws and regulations governing the resolution of large, complex, non-bank financial institutions, and secondly, some antitrust issues related to the approval of bank mergers. With respect to the first, I want to focus a bit on the decision-making process in reality that produces bailouts. Experience has shown that political risk aversion favors bailouts even when they are not necessary and is too generous in the bailouts when they are performed. Which regulator will be willing to risk a systemic meltdown on their watch and face the potential political backlash that would accompany it if they have ready-made taxpayer funds that they can pay out instead? Creditors of failing non-bank financial institutions are aware of policy-makers' risk aversion, demonstrated by the series of bailouts beginning in 1984, with what is now widely regarded as a political and regulatory overreaction to the failure of Continental Bank, the first example of the application of the too-big-to-fail doctrine. Creditors use that risk aversion to exaggerate their own vulnerability to shocks and to obtain more generous protection from taxpayers. A Washington Post article that came out today, written after my testimony, has the following quote in it in discussing the AIG bailout and why creditors received no haircuts in the AIG bailout. Quote--this is a quote from the New York Fed's general counsel, who was part of the negotiation--"In its negotiations with its counterparties, AIG just didn't have the same bargaining power that it did with the Federal Reserve standing in the background. The only sensible outcome was to give them what they were legally entitled to.'' In other words, zero haircuts. I would be happy to talk with you more about that. But what the general counsel of the New York Fed is saying is when the Fed is involved, we are just not tough negotiators. And I think that is exactly what happened in the AIG bailout. Bailouts, as most recently illustrated by AIG's experience, keep counterparties and creditors whole because there is no way, short of bankruptcy, under current law to force them to bear a loss. In other words, the game of chicken between government agencies and creditors is one that the government is likely to lose, as they did with AIG's creditors, when trying to convince creditors to share in losses, which means taxpayers end up bearing all the loss. Now, there is broad consensus that this status quo is not acceptable, and we all understand it is not going to be changed just by bold statements. Reform must create a means to transfer the control of assets and operations of a failed institution in an orderly way while ensuring that shareholders and creditors of the failing firm suffer large losses. Those outcomes are essential if the resolution of failure is to avoid significant disruptions to third parties and also avoid bailout costs to taxpayers accompanying the--the bailout. Two approaches have been suggested--one, bankruptcy reforms, and two, the creation of an administrative resolution authority. Critics of creating an administrative resolution authority rightly argue that placing discretionary authority over resolution in a regulator is likely to institutionalize generous, too-big-to-fail protection, just as I have argued it would. But despite the arguments that I believe favor bankruptcy reform as an approach, it is not clear whether the government can credibly pursue a pure bankruptcy approach even if doing so were economically desirable. The problem is a political one. An economically defensible tough-love bankruptcy system might encourage, for reasons associated with political risk aversion, ad-hoc resolutions to occur outside the reform bankruptcy process, just like AIG. And for that reason, I believe it would be desirable to establish a hybrid bankruptcy resolution approach which predefines and thereby constrains the way administrative resolution would occur. I am part of a bipartisan task force put together by the Pew Trusts, which is about to release a report, a large part of which has to do with how to structure such a bipartisan compromise that would create this hybrid resolution. And I will be happy to discuss it more. It is referenced a bit in my testimony. I know I am running out of time. I want to focus briefly on what to do about antitrust. In my testimony, I describe my own experience as an advisor to the attorneys general of Massachusetts and Connecticut and the problem there with the politicization of the antitrust process in the case of the Fleet-BankBoston merger. My conclusion from that is that we need to have undivided authority vested in the Justice Department Antitrust Division, and it needs to have budgetary autonomy. The Fed needs to get out of the process, and we need to make sure that the Justice Department is politically protected. Thank you very much. [The prepared statement of Mr. Calomiris follows:] Prepared Statement of Charles W. Calomiris [GRAPHICS NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT] __________ Mr. Johnson. Thank you. Professor Sagers, proponents of the bill have argued that this bill has essentially the same limitations on antitrust as the FDIA, and wanted to ask you, since we are now in the questioning period and all Members will abide by the 5-minute rule, is that accurate? Mr. Sagers. Yes, in one important respect it is incorrect. As I explain in my written statement, it is a very complicated question, but a simple answer is that the claim that the bill does not modify current antitrust review--that claim is incorrect for the simple reason that under current law transfers of banking assets--"banking assets"--are subject to a special regime of antitrust review which is undertaken by both the banking agencies and the Justice Department jointly. And in some respects it is a little bit different than the more familiar merger review process under the Hart-Scott-Rodino Act and sometimes it can be made to go a little bit faster than HSR review. However, where non-banking assets are transferred in almost all cases, including some securities and insurance businesses, other financial businesses--when those transactions occur, the ordinary Hart-Scott-Rodino process applies. And importantly, when the Justice Department or the Federal Trade Commission reviews a transaction, reviews a transfer of non-banking assets, they have a lot of power. They have a lot of essentially civil discovery power to force the merging parties to disclose information. They can also request information from third parties. And I believe, most importantly, they can essentially force the merger--force the transaction to slow down so that they can take the time they feel they need to address anticompetitive concerns. Okay. So that is the piece that would be changed under bill under the resolution authority where FDIC causes the sale of some non-banking asset that is owned by a failing financial company in receivership. That transaction would be subject to HSR, except that the agencies would not be permitted to make the so-called second request for more information, which has the result of both giving them more information and slowing the process down. As I explained, I happen to think that is really a pretty big deal. It is a pretty big change, because in effect the agencies are going to be forced to review what could be very large mergers or acquisitions in 30 calendar days, with probably quite limited information. Mr. Johnson. Thank you. I would like to ask everyone on the panel to respond to this question, starting with Professor Calomiris. Does the resolution authority have the effect of institutionalizing too- big-to-fail companies as part of the economy? And is this a problem? Mr. Calomiris. It all depends, Mr. Chairman, on how it is structured. If it is a backstop protection, as I am proposing, and, crucially, if there is a requirement of minimal haircuts to creditors and, furthermore, if triggering the use of the resolution authority has to be approved by Congress and, finally, if the large financial institutions that presumably benefit from this protection have to pay for it after the protections applied, so it is not the taxpayers paying for it but the financial system, then I think we can say it doesn't institutionalize too big to fail. But if you don't add all those caveats, you will institutionalize too big to fail. Mr. Johnson. Thank you. Mr. Rosenthal? Mr. Rosenthal. Yes. I believe it does not institutionalize too big to fail but, again, subject to the statements that I made before, that we need to layer onto what is already--what has already been proposed bankruptcy code concepts that impose judicial restraint in some instances, that impose factors that limit the ability of the regulator to go too far and that subject companies to restrictions that they and their creditors agree to. Mr. Smith. Let me try this one. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I also agree that this should not institutionalize too big to fail, especially if creditors and shareholders will be suffering a loss as part of the process. The only caveat I have relates to what happens when you have a business that, at its core, relates to systemic risk and where it may be necessary to transfer the assets of that business with certain liabilities being assumed. Now, if you are one of the creditors who is extending credit to one of the businesses that does not fall into that category, you know that you are going to suffer a loss even if the business is too big to fail. But if you are one of those creditors who is extending credit to the part of the business that is a core systemic risk asset, I think there needs to be a lot of thought given as to whether that creditor's claim is going to be assumed in its entirety as part of the rescue process and, if so, whether there is an element of institutionalizing the too big to fail scheme for that creditor that needs to be taken into account. So I would suggest caution in that area. But as a general matter, this is legislation that one hopes would never be invoked in the future. Mr. Johnson. Yes. Thank you, Mr. Smith. And, Professor Sagers? Mr. Sagers. Thank you. I really would just repeat what Professor Calomiris said. It seems to me the question really depends on how the act is administered. The act seems to me to give one agency an extraordinary amount of flexibility and its administration, it seems to me, is going to be subject to some degree to changing political forces, depending on changes in Administrations. I would add that I think that problem, like other problems, could be improved under this act if it is--if it strengthens antitrust review under Hart-Scott-Rodino Act. Mr. Johnson. All right. Thank you, gentlemen. My time has expired. I will now proceed to Mr. Chaffetz for questions. Mr. Chaffetz. Thank you, Chairman. I would ask, actually, unanimous consent to insert into the record, if I could, a statement from the Ranking Member of the overall Judiciary Committee, Member Lamar Smith. If I could insert those into the record---- Mr. Johnson. Without objection. [The prepared statement of Mr. Smith follows:] Prepared Statement of the Honorable Lamar Smith, a Representative in Congress from the State of Texas, and Ranking Member, Committee on the Judiciary [GRAPHICS NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT] __________ Mr. Chaffetz. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I want to go back to you, Mr.--Professor Calomiris--am I pronouncing your name properly? I hope so. Okay. Mr. Calomiris. Calomiris, yes. Mr. Chaffetz. Yes. Are you familiar with H.R. 3310 and what that uses as the foundation for reform in the bankruptcy code? Could you talk specifically to that and your impression of that? Mr. Calomiris. Yes. I have reviewed it. I couldn't recite every part of it to you from memory, but I liked it. But I don't think it goes far enough. I mentioned three things in my testimony that I think would be additional reforms to the bankruptcy process, especially as applied to a new--let's call it Chapter 14--applied to non-bank financial institutions. And so I could go over those. One of them has to do with dealing with voting problems that have emerged in the recent CIT bankruptcy case. So we have to worry now about creditors who have offsetting hedged positions or maybe even over-hedged positions so that they have an incentive in disrupting the bankruptcy process. So you might want to change the law so that your net position determines your voting power, not your gross position as a creditor. That is just one example, and that is not just for financial institutions. We need to be worrying about that more broadly. We also have to worry about the problem of international coordination. And it is not good enough just to say let's worry about it. We actually have to figure out a way over a short period of time that we can figure out where assets are going to reside. A big problem in the Lehman bankruptcy was that a lot of assets came back overnight. Nobody knew, are they part of the New York jurisdiction or are they going back to other countries? You have to have as part of the living will that is being proposed--and I support that idea--cooperation, pre-agreement among regulators in advance, as to how they are going to figure out where assets and liabilities reside if the bankruptcy happens. And I had another point, but I will stop there talking. Mr. Chaffetz. Okay. Mr. Rosenthal, I want to give you a moment here to expand on this idea of flexibility but predictability and how those two are able to balance in such a way to achieve what we are trying to achieve. Can you---- Mr. Rosenthal. Yes, and actually, interestingly, the way we have tried to come up with the hybrid approach could be implemented through a new regime, or it could also be implemented through a revision to the bankruptcy code. What we have envisioned here to get flexibility is have a period of time--call it an exclusive period, a crisis period-- where the FDIC--whatever the regulatory agency is--takes over the business, does what it has to do in terms of selling it to--or transferring it, or capitalizing it to avert a financial crisis, without supervision of a court, which enables the action to be taken quicker, doesn't require all of the notice of the bankruptcy proceeding. That is the flexibility. But then you come to the point of how is the rest of the case going to continue, and is there any judicial supervision or oversight, even on an after-the-fact basis, of the actions that were taken during the exclusive period. So the way that we have built in the predictability is to say that all of the things that would occur after this initial period are effectively managed and run and supervised the same way they would be under the bankruptcy code--bankruptcy court is there, bankruptcy court looks at the thing. And even the actions that were taken during that initial period could be brought forward later before the bankruptcy court if a creditor was able to demonstrate that as a result of the actions that were taken it is in a worse position down the road than it was in on day one if the actions had not been taken. Mr. Chaffetz. Okay. Thank you. Sorry, time is so short. Going back to Mr. Calomiris, if I could, please, let's talk a little bit about the case study that is first and foremost on a lot of people's mind, which is AIG. I just want to give you a moment to further expand on that thought, and know that we probably have less than a minute here before my time expires. Mr. Calomiris. Well, I think the really important lesson from the combination of AIG and Lehman was, first of all, that a big part of the problem with Lehman, which was related to-- they all happened simultaneously--was the anticipation of protection. And Lehman would have gone to the market in March of 2008 and raised capital after the Bear Stearns failure if it didn't expect to be protected. That is the big lesson. We don't want to have that expectation. And then AIG proved it. Even though Lehman didn't get protected, that was a mistake that--you know, many people regard as a mistake. I don't, but the problem is now people do regard that as a mistake, and the solution to it is going to look--unless we have very hard language that prevents it, it is going to look a lot like AIG. AIG's UBS counterparty was willing to take a 2 percent haircut. That was very, very big of them--willing to take a 2 percent haircut on their positions. Nobody else was. And the Fed spent, as far as I can tell, about 30 seconds negotiating with them and then decided to tell UBS they didn't even have to take the 2 percent haircut they offered because they decided it was simpler for them just to make a one-size- fits-all, nobody takes a haircut. That sent a hugely bad message to creditors in the future. It was unnecessary. But what I want to emphasize is not that, you know, Tim Geithner was a bad guy because he did that. What I want to emphasize is he wasn't playing with his money. He was playing with mine and yours. And he is not a very tough negotiator because as a regulator his incentives will always be to do that. That is what we need to be worried about if we empower discretionary authority outside of bankruptcy. Now, some people on the panel here have talked about the need to protect creditors' rights. I understand that, and I favor reform of the bankruptcy code as the dominant way to do this. But I also worry about protecting taxpayers' rights. Mr. Chaffetz. Thank you. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I appreciate your indulgence in allowing us to go over time a little bit. Thank you. Mr. Johnson. Certainly. Thank you, Mr. Chaffetz. Now I recognize the esteemed gentleman from Michigan, the Chair of the Judiciary Committee, the honorable John Conyers. Mr. Conyers. Thank you. One of the problems is that the Finance Committee is marking up their bill right now, and I keep thinking about the barn door syndrome here. And I am trying to figure out what this Committee--this part of Judiciary can do about it and what--when I meet with Chairman Frank that we want to keep working on. So at the same time that I am omitting the fact that we should have really held this part of the hearing before them so that they got an idea--their frame of reference is fixed. All this good testimony they may look at some day after it. I see that bankruptcy is being minimized in this regulatory finance package. I see that we are going to have a situation where we may be sorry about not being strong enough. I am impressed with the witnesses here who I hear telling me that it is more than about patching up the system, it is the--it is to put in safeguards so that this won't happen again. You can patch it up--and this isn't the first time we have been to the brink either. All of you know better than we--we can create a remedy, a regulatory remedy, that still makes the same thing that doesn't limit the possibility of this happening again. So the question that I have for you four is what more can we do, and of course, I don't ever stop--we are not going to stop just because they are marking up their bill. There is going to be lots of negotiations. Only heaven knows what the other body is going to produce. There will be a rules committee where lights frequently go out. There will be a conference committee. So I want you to tell me what we ought to do, because we haven't mentioned Glass-Steagall and the little sorry Bliley effort that succeeded it. I mean, I am not comfortable about this, and I want you to give me not only your best advice here today, but I would like the honor of us being in touch as this moves down the road. This isn't going to happen before next year. I know there is great intentions for moving with swiftness. Sagers and Calomiris, why don't you start off this discussion? I ask unanimous consent for a little more time, Mr. Chairman. Mr. Johnson. Without objection. Mr. Sagers. Yes. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I hate to be a one-trick pony, and I also sort of hate to say this, because I really don't know how controversial this sort of thing might be to say. I take heart that if I understand him, Professor Calomiris said something similar. I personally think that the regime of bank merger law we have right now needs to be reopened, and I would favor getting rid of it. To the extent that it ever had a justification, it is now a very strained justification that I think many people don't find very persuasive, and bank mergers could take place under the ordinary Hart-Scott-Rodino Act. That leaves open the large problem, though, that as the Justice Department and the banking agencies have interpreted their duties under bank merger law--that is, as they have understood their substantive job in reviewing bank mergers, which undoubtedly would--they would carry over. I mean, if you do away with bank merger law and say everything is subject to Hart-Scott-Rodino, the same theoretical approach that has been applied under bank merger law would continue to be applied under Hart-Scott-Rodino, unless Congress were to take some action to correct that. And the problem is traditionally both the banking regulators and the Justice Department for a long time have believed--and in their defense, they believe it on the basis of a fair amount of empirical evidence--they believe that, by and large, competition issues relevant to Section 7 just aren't very serious in these markets. That is, the only cases in which we have serious competition issues are in local markets serving consumers, mainly, the sort of retail lending needs of consumers and small businesses. Everything else we can take to be presumptively highly competitive and therefore those mergers don't raise any concerns. I am not really prepared to offer ideas on how that should be corrected, but I think that it is mistaken even in the traditional respect--that is, it is mistaken even in its assumptions about whether particular banking markets are competitive. But also, let me just reemphasize--this is a bit of a pie in the sky sort of argument that academics get to make and nobody else does because they are difficult, I guess. But we don't have any laws, really, that directly deal with the problem of systemic risk being increased by mergers and acquisitions. When companies get together and get bigger, thereby increasing systemic risk, to my knowledge there is no really effective regime other than Clayton Act Section 7 to address that, and Clayton Act Section 7 hasn't been used in that way. Mr. Conyers. But banks are exempted under Hart. Mr. Sagers. That is true. Mr. Conyers. You haven't mentioned that. I mean, you keep relying on it, but they have got a hole as big as a tank to drive through Hart-Scott-Rodino. Mr. Sagers. Yes, and my suggestion would be issue number one ought to be closing that loophole. Technically, bank mergers are subject to this--a substantive standard, a legal substantive standard very similar to the one that is applied under Clayton Act Section 7. Mr. Conyers. Well, technically, but it doesn't happen in real time. Professor Calomiris? Mr. Calomiris. Yes. I agree with you about the loophole. The way I experienced it, which I described in my testimony, was that I was working for the attorneys general of Massachusetts and Connecticut. And I showed them in my study--I predicted that if they allowed Fleet and BankBoston to merge, middle market borrowers, meaning the backbone firms, small businesses and middle-market businesses in the U.S.--would experience an increase of a full 1 percent on their loans' cost if they did, and that that is who was complaining about the merger. It wasn't hidden. Those were the people complaining, and those were the people who were going to suffer. After the merger happened, it went up exactly 1 percent. So it wasn't rocket science. It wasn't difficult to see. What was lacking was the political will, because the problem is mergers create a lot of cookies, and people like cookies, and they come, frankly, to Congress and they ask people to help them get some of the cookies. And then in this case the Antitrust Division of the Justice Department was leaned on by a Member of Congress, who said, ``If you guys fight this, it is going to hurt you in your budget for antitrust.'' And it was a very embarrassing thing for the Antitrust Division, because I am on the phone with them 1 day, and they are ready, gung-ho, an the next day they say, ``We are not gung-ho anymore.'' And that is why I emphasize--I am not a lawyer but I am an economist, so I emphasize budgetary independence. If you are serious about this, that is what it is going to take, because that is where--what I saw. Now, I want to say another---- Mr. Conyers. Now, what is this piece of history--how does this tie into the regulatory reform act that is being--is on the stove being cooked up right now? Mr. Calomiris. It should be added in, and I don't see it. Mr. Conyers. What should be added in? Mr. Calomiris. The kind of reform that, in my view, would take away from the Fed and place in the Antitrust Division undivided authority and budgetary autonomy to strengthen protection for all the various consumers, including businesses and small businesses. And I think, really, the biggest concern right now--I think Professor Sagers agreed with me, or someone did--is these middle-sized businesses which in many parts of the country are not getting served. You need to have a couple, at least, or three or four large banks in every location to be able to have real competition for middle market lending, and we don't have that. Mr. Conyers. Mr. Rosenthal, how do you weigh in on this discussion? Mr. Rosenthal. Mr. Chairman, first, I think this issue is not going to go away. If you are lucky enough that it disappears in the rules committee, maybe, but I think we have a problem that needs a resolution. We have the bankruptcy code that deals with the rights of creditors. We have the FDIA that deals with the rights of depositors. Neither one of those deal with systemic risk. So I think if you want to be--if you want to be productive and you do not think that you can overcome the majority with respect to a bill that takes power out of the bankruptcy code and creates a new resolution authority, then you have to make proposals that build in the protections that we have been talking about. So for example, we have--and we would love to talk to you about it further--I have done some summaries of changes that would be inserted into this bill that would, in fact, provide the protections--a number of the protections that Mr. Smith and I at least talked about in terms of judicial---- Mr. Conyers. For example? Mr. Rosenthal [continuing]. Review, claims determination. For example, a provision that would require judicial review, that would, in effect, make the bankruptcy court the arbiter of decisions from--you know, after this exclusive period that I was talking about. A provision that would require that claims determinations first be the subject of a negotiation between the FDIC, but if they could not reach a resolution then you would do what we do in the bankruptcy code--court all the time. You would go to the bankruptcy court and you would say, ``Bankruptcy court, decide how this--decide this claim. What is the amount of the claim?" Issues about valuation--clearly, secured creditors bargain for collateral to support their obligations. The bill deals somewhat with the rights of secured creditors, but it doesn't say how you would value their claims. We would build in--we think you should build in provisions that if you can't agree with the regulatory authority about the value of the secured claim, you go to the bankruptcy court. Mr. Conyers. Can the rest of our witnesses buy into that modification? Mr. Smith. I certainly can. This was, indeed, part of my testimony on behalf of the National Bankruptcy Conference. But I do want to add something in terms of the broader perspective that you are raising, Mr. Conyers. You were saying how can this legislation be devised so that what happened doesn't happen again. And looking at this purely from the bankruptcy standpoint is almost like asking an undertaker what he could have done to have prevented the death of the deceased. The bankruptcy is the back-end side of things. And there is an important element that Mr. Rosenthal has mentioned, which is you want to have transparent, clear, fair rules for creditors to ensure predictability so that the market starts to adjust for true credit risk and does not take into account the fact that there are no consequences for creditors who make bad credit decisions, as Professor Calomiris had mentioned. But even beyond that, part of this bill has to be prudential regulation at the outset, maybe in the area of antitrust that was just discussed, but maybe broader regulation as well, so that there are limits on some of the risk-taking that can be made in this economy. Thank you. Mr. Calomiris. I want to give a hopeful note here and tell you that in about 2 days the Pew Trusts bipartisan task force on financial reform is going to release a report. I am a member of that. It is a bipartisan group. Democrats who are members of that include Alice Rivlin, former vice governor of the Fed; Alan Blinder, also former vice governor of the Fed; Bob Litan; Rodgin Cohen, Sullivan & Cromwell; Morris Goldstein. We have about a dozen people, and we have reached consensus. We have a platform. It is not identical to the Frank bill. It is not identical to the Dodd bill. It does share a lot in common with them. There are good ideas in those bills. But the details are not often very good. Intellectually, what you are seeing here today, I think, is a lot of consensus across the aisle, and what is really interesting is I have lived through that for the past 6 months in the Pew task force. I think if Congress would just slow down on both sides of-- both houses, and just listen to that bipartisan consensus, you could do a lot better than either of those bills. And I think the problem is the devil is in the details, and he really is in those details right now. We need to fix those. Mr. Conyers. Yes, we will be looking forward to the Pew report. And I thank you for the time, Mr. Chairman. Could I just close with one--let me just ask you, we have got some strong personalities involved in this legislation--Dodd, Frank, Shelby--and I wish Stiglitz could have been here to join you to make it five instead of four. How do you separate out what we have been talking about from what they seem to be advocating? Mr. Calomiris. I am willing to take a crack at it. I think that there are good things, as I said, in--I have talked to people on both sides of the aisle, and I am actually very hopeful. I think people can come together on a bipartisan consensus. I really do. I don't think that any of the positions and the differences are insurmountable. I think I don't want to speak out of school and mention particular lawmakers that I have talked to, but I am actually confident of it. I think the key, though, is don't rush it through. Give it a little bit of time. Instead of trying to get a bill done by February that is going to have to be done on an egotistical or partisan basis, give it till March or--and you will have a bipartisan one. Mr. Rosenthal. I would agree with that, and I will just point to one provision of the bill. If you look at the proposal--and this is in a number of the proposals--frankly, all of the proposals that have been introduced--you see one provision that says claim determinations are not subject to judicial review, and you see another proposal that says claim determinations are subject to judicial review. I think that highlights what Professor Calomiris has been saying, that you need to take the time to go through this legislation and, one, make it consistent and, two, make sure that it embodies characteristics that both guard against systemic risk, which I think everybody would agree is a problem, and that protect creditors' interests as well. Mr. Conyers. Well, look, the Chairman on the--in the other body has a seriously different view from the Chairman in this body. I am glad to have words of hope. And I mentioned Mr. Shelby. I know he doesn't--I don't say I know--I think he doesn't agree with either one of them. So let's work through this a little bit. None of them are saying what you have been saying about bankruptcy and how we we resolve--how we make Hart-Scott-Rodino more effective. Glass- Steagall--that is like something out of the past. I am not sure how far memory goes back on these subjects. So I don't know where the optimism seems to be coming from. I just hope you are right, but it is not at all clear to me. So I thank you, Mr. Chairman, for your indulgence. Mr. Johnson. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. There is a call to have a second round of questions, so I will begin that second round with Mr. Chaffetz. Mr. Chaffetz. Thank you. I appreciate it, Mr. Chairman-- such an important subject. I want to just offer one kind of two-part question, and then if you can just kind of go down the line and--and address it, do you think that an extended period of legal uncertainty could actually undermine the availability of credit to businesses as we try to emerge from the current recession? And the second part of that is if you think that another meltdown hits before the legal uncertainty is cleared up, the legal uncertainty could actually impair our ability to control such a meltdown? I would appreciate your perspective on that. Just kind of left from right. Mr. Sagers. You know, thank you. I guess my immediate reaction is in studying this bill, and in studying a lot of related legal topics, that is precisely the kind of concern that is consistently--I am not saying it is true in this case, but it is consistently overstated with rhetorical purposes in mind--that is, with achieving certain consequences. I gather a person stating such an argument, at least during a period like this one, when policy reform is on the table, would be making that claim with the point of urging haste. I think that would be a mistake in this case, and I just want to sort of incorporate something Professor Calomiris said on this before. I think he said it well, and he is much more expert in it than I am. Thank you. Mr. Smith. Thank you. I come at this from a long history of law reform where I was advised very early on that one of the primary goals of law reform is to do no harm. And it is very easy to try to address a specific problem and find out that you are creating other problems that are totally unforeseen. I think there is a greater risk here in haste. It is true that a period of uncertainty will affect the availability of credit and will affect the cost of credit, but that problem could be compounded if the wrong legislation were enacted. Mr. Rosenthal. I would agree with that. I think that there is more problem--yes, I think there is--it is worse and you compound the problem to rush to judgment and implement legislation which itself may be very uncertain than whatever legal uncertainty currently exists. We have a system that does work to some extent. It may have some problems, but we know the system. We understand the system. Creditors understand the system. Businesses understand the system. Courts understand the system. Courts worked through Lehman, even though they had to work, you know, all night, day and night, for weeks. They worked through Lehman. They worked through G.M. They worked through Chrysler. And they did it quickly. So to me, you would delay a decision and come to a more reasoned decision than rush something through. Mr. Calomiris. I agree with what has been said by the other three. I would just point to a couple of things. When we had the clarification after September 2008 by FASB of how they--the regulations in terms of mark to market would be applied--that clarification was extremely helpful to the markets, because it told people that they didn't have to go into a death spiral of valuation based on some existing market price. That resolved a very big legal uncertainty about the appropriate way to apply that, and it was very helpful. I would also say that the stress tests resolved a regulatory enforcement uncertainty. More than they provided information about the condition of the banks, they really told us how the regulators were planning to behave toward the banks, and that was hugely beneficial. So what we know from just looking at the recent crisis is moments of regulatory enforcement uncertainty or rules uncertainty can be devastating. And I also agree with Mr. Rosenthal that actually aside from the issues associated with international coordination of which assets belong where, the Lehman bankruptcy actually gives us a fairly good feeling about the ability of the bankruptcy code to deal with things. So I look at it as we have workable problems. We have problems that we could actually deal with but that we need to focus on. Mr. Chaffetz. Yes, I yield to Mr. Goodlatte. Mr. Goodlatte. Yes, I wanted to follow up. Do you think that if they had made that clarification much earlier in this process that it would have had that same settling beneficial effect that you noted that it had when they finally got around to doing that late last fall? I mean, we here in the Congress struggled with this all through this crisis, and the votes we had on bailout bills and so on, saying that market to market was a significant contributor to the uncertainty and that addressing that early and quickly would have had a very salutary effect? Mr. Calomiris. Yes, I do. Mr. Goodlatte. Thank you. Mr. Chaffetz. And let me just say, Mr. Chairman, as I wrap up, I appreciate the kind of what I perceive as unanimous conclusion that it is most important to get it right rather than get it done fast, that there are unintended consequences of overreacting and reacting too quickly without understanding all of the ramifications. I think that is precisely the point that I would like to make, that there is a system that, by and large, works, that no doubt there needs to be reform, and we are trying to address that. But, Mr. Chairman, we ought to be understanding--thoroughly understanding each and every act and consequence so that we don't misstep and create unintended consequences that we will suffer from for years to come. So thank you for your time. Mr. Johnson. Thank you, Congressman. I have got a couple of questions. In the case of a non-bank entity that is too big to fail, who--how would the process work under the bill that is being marked up now in Financial Services? How would this work? And I will say that when a bank is teetering on the brink of insolvency you would have, you know, some notices that would have gone out to the bank saying you need to do this, or you need to do that, and then after a period of time then the regulators would swoop in, I guess without notice, and take over the bank, and then find some entity that would purchase the bank. What would be the process of determining what entity is too big to fail, why--who would make that assessment, and--I will rest with that. And anyone who wants to answer that question is certainly welcome to. Mr. Smith. I will start off by saying that my understanding of how the too-big-to-fail institution would be identified would be--we will know it when we see it, if I understand it, that there are a number of different agencies that need to collaborate in the form of a council that would make that judgment, and the bill spells out the factors that need to be taken into consideration. But in the end of the day I would be curious whether the other panelists see things differently--it is a pure judgment made by the best authorities who could view the problem. Mr. Rosenthal. And, Mr. Chairman, if you--some of the attachments to my testimony reflect an overview of--and a comparative summary of how that decision gets made under the current bill. It is basically a recommendation by the FDIC, approved by the Secretary of the Treasury, in consultation with the President, and they have to make certain findings about that collapse would be--you know, would cause a systemic difficulty. That is the technical things that happen. The practical things that happen I think are a little different. We know how bank failures occur because we have a whole--a number of years of precedent about how banks are taken over. It is a little bit unclear how, as a practical matter, this would occur. But you would expect that it wouldn't be swooping in, you know, in--at midnight for companies that are this large and this significant, that there would be significant discussions between the FDIC or the Fed or--and others---- Mr. Johnson. Including the target? Mr. Rosenthal. I would think so, because just as there was with Lehman, you know, just as there undoubtedly was with Bear, just as there has been with AIG, I think there would be discussions with the target company to see if there were ways to avert the problem short of declaring the company to be a systemically significant company and subjecting it to this resolution authority. But ultimately, if there were no other--there were no other solution, or if management of the company, for example, were unwilling to implement other solutions, then I could see these recommendations being made. Remember that in a bankruptcy, the way you get into bankruptcy is that the--either your creditors put you in through the filing of an involuntary or the company voluntarily files a bankruptcy case. There isn't a provision, at least in current law, for the FDIC or the Treasury or the United States to put a company into bankruptcy. What this new regime would do is say that there would be discussions--if the company wouldn't take the action that the government wanted, or there wasn't an action short of--you know, short of using this authority, that you could use this authority to resolve these companies and essentially depose management. Mr. Calomiris. Under what I think is going to be reported on Friday by the Pew task force, it would work the following way--similar in some ways to the resolution authority in the two different bills right now, but I think the details are kind of important. First of all, let's say that on a particular day, Friday, a non--a large non-bank financial institution looks like it is in trouble, it is having problems. How do we know that? What would happen is it would have trouble finding counterparties to deal with it in the market. And then I would expect the President, in consultation with the Secretary of the Treasury, would decide whether he wanted to appeal to Congress to make this firm exempted from the bankruptcy. So now we can go in one of two ways. If the President decides not to, then what happens in bankruptcy? Under the Chapter 14 as I would see it reformed, the Fed would be able to do debtor-in-possession financing during a--some period of time while the bankruptcy court was able to take charge of the process. There are already QFCs. Certain contracts are exempted from a bankruptcy stay. It might make sense to change the rules a little bit to allow people who are willing--short-term contracts that are maturing to take large haircuts in exchange for also being exempted as QFCs are. There are lots of interesting details, because we don't want the financial system to freeze up because of the networking of claims that have to be traded. So there may be some reforms for the bankruptcy process--I didn't get through all of them--that are helpful in that. Then, or if we are not going to go in that direction, if the President thinks we need to have a resolution authority, it is going to now proceed in a way where the creditors know that by law they cannot be made whole because, for example, under the Dodd bill--the Dodd bill now says there has to be a minimal haircut. Unfortunately, it gives a loophole that says that unless the FDIC decides there is a systemic problem they can waive that. So there are lots of problems. I don't support that loophole. But if they did proceed that way, creditors would know that either way they are going to have a loss. That would be very beneficial. And I would predict that the resolution authority-- the regulator--would end up imposing the legally mandated minimum loss. They are not going to be aggressive enough. And so it is--if you put in that minimum loss, then they will be imposed. And if you don't put it in, it won't be imposed. Mr. Johnson. Let me ask this question. Assuming a target has been in negotiations with the resolution authority, but then decides that it is in its best interest to file a Chapter 11 petition, which I suppose has an automatic stay feature-- okay--would the resolution authority under the current bills being considered have authority to trump the bankruptcy court? Mr. Rosenthal. Yes. What happens is that the--if resolution authority is exercised, then that company becomes ineligible to be a debtor in a Chapter 11 case. So it effectively trumps the bankruptcy code. Mr. Johnson. All right. I have no further questions. Next, Mr. Chairman, anything further? I will say that the--we may as well bring this to a close. I do appreciate you all's appearance before us today and I would like to thank you for your testimony. Without objection, Members will have 5 legislative days to submit any additional written questions which we will forward to the witnesses and ask that you answer as promptly as you can, to be made a part of the record. Without objection, the record will be kept open for 5 legislative days for the submission of any other--any additional materials. Today's hearing raised a number of important issues and certainly there--I don't know if February or March or April would be sufficient time to iron out all of the details. But as we consider this proposed legislation, we would do well to consider whether the absence of sufficient antitrust and judicial protections in emergency situations creates larger problems that it--than it seeks to solve. And with that, this hearing of the Subcommittee on Courts and Competition Policy is adjourned. [Whereupon, at 2:34 p.m., the Subcommittee was adjourned.]